« Back to article | Print this article |
But the budget crisis in Greece and the risk of insolvency in Italy and Spain are just part of the problem caused by the single currency.
The fragility of the major European banks, high unemployment rates, and the large intra-European trade imbalance (Germany's $200 billion current-account surplus versus the combined $300 billion current-account deficit in the rest of the euro zone) also reflect the use of the euro.
European politicians who insisted on introducing the euro in 1999 ignored the warnings of economists who predicted that a single currency for all of Europe would create serious problems.
Click NEXT to read more...
The euro's advocates were focused on the goal of European political integration, and saw the single currency as part of the process of creating a sense of political community in Europe.
They rallied popular support with the slogan "One Market, One Money", arguing that the free-trade area created by the European Union would succeed only with a single currency.
Neither history nor economic logic supported that view. Indeed, EU trade functions well, despite the fact that only 17 of the Union's 27 members use the euro.
But the key argument made by European officials and other defenders of the euro has been that, because a single currency works well in the United States, it should also work well in Europe. After all, both are large, continental, and diverse economies.
Click NEXT to read more...
But that argument overlooks three important differences between the US and Europe.
First, the US is effectively a single labour market, with workers moving from areas of high and rising unemployment to places where jobs are more plentiful.
In Europe, national labour markets are effectively separated by barriers of language, culture, religion, union membership, and social-insurance systems.
To be sure, some workers in Europe do migrate. In the absence of the high degree of mobility seen in the US, however, overall unemployment can be lowered only if high-unemployment countries can ease monetary policy, an option precluded by the single currency.
Click NEXT to read more...
A second important difference is that the US has a centralised fiscal system. Individuals and businesses pay the majority of their taxes to the federal government in Washington, rather than to their state (or local) authorities.
When a US state's economic activity slows relative to the rest of the country, the taxes that its individuals and businesses pay to the federal government decline, and the funds that it receives from the federal government (for unemployment benefits and other transfer programmes) increase.
Roughly speaking, each dollar of GDP decline in a state like Massachusetts or Ohio triggers changes in taxes and transfers that offset about 40 cents of that drop, providing a substantial fiscal stimulus.
Click NEXT to read more...
There is no comparable offset in Europe, where taxes are almost exclusively paid to, and transfers received from, national governments.
The EU's Maastricht Treaty specifically reserves this tax-and-transfer authority to the member states, a reflection of Europeans' unwillingness to transfer funds to other countries' people in the way that Americans are willing to do among people in different states.
The third important difference is that all US states are required by their constitutions to balance their annual operating budgets.
While "rainy day" funds that accumulate in boom years are used to deal with temporary revenue shortfalls, the states' "general obligation" borrowing is limited to capital projects like roads and schools.
Click NEXT to read more...
Even a state like California, seen by many as a poster child for fiscal profligacy, now has an annual budget deficit of just one per cent of its GDP and a general obligation debt of just four per cent of GDP.
These limits on state-level budget deficits are a logical implication of the fact that US states cannot create money to fill fiscal gaps.
These constitutional rules prevent the kind of deficit and debt problems that have beset the euro zone, where capital markets ignored individual countries' lack of monetary independence.
Click NEXT to read more...
None of these features of the US economy would develop in Europe even if the eurozone evolved into a more explicitly political union.
Although the form of political union advocated by Germany and others remains vague, it would not involve centralised revenue collection, as in the US, because that would place a greater burden on German taxpayers to finance government programs in other countries.
Nor would political union enhance labour mobility within the euro zone, overcome the problems caused by imposing a common monetary policy on countries with different cyclical conditions, or improve the trade performance of countries that cannot devalue their exchange rates to regain competitiveness.
Click NEXT to read more..
The most likely effect of strengthening political union in the euro zone would be to give Germany the power to control the other members' budgets and prescribe changes in their taxes and spending.
This formal transfer of sovereignty would only increase the tensions and conflicts that already exist between Germany and other EU countries.
The author is professor of economics at Harvard, was previously chairman of President Ronald Reagan's Council of Economic Advisers and is former president of the National Bureau for Economic Research.
© Project Syndicate, 2011